|
Released on July 02, 2014, 11:30 PM EDT
Tag #: 670
City in crisis: Systemic
problem at City hall
The
politics of ‘entitlement’: Eating
well on taxpayers’ dime…

Ron Dupuis
: Breach
of trust
Sudbury
citizens are all working hard to bring meals to their table, while
Greater Sudbury`s Councilor and Mayoral Candidate, Ron Dupuis, is
not flattering to the city’s image and it is a crying shame. All
of the criticism boils down to the politics of ‘entitlement’—
the reported financial advantages acquired by the councilor on
“incidental expenses.” Dupuis took excessive advantage of his
political position over the past decade of his service through the
taxpayer’s dime. The
councilors relied on a salary formula tied to the city
administration salary grid that increased each year. |
The
politics of ‘entitlement’ raised the eyebrows of taxpayers. Are
taxpayers expected to foot the bill to feed the councilor? Taxpayers have
already paid him to do the job that he is supposed to do in his office.
This entitlement and abuse of spending cannot be tolerated any longer.
WikiLeaks
Sudbury uncovered that detail concerning Dupuis’ incidental expenses for
meals. Dupuis spent $ 1059.83.36 in 2010 (see
leaked incidental expense form 01) and $ 835.66 in
2011 (see leaked
incidental expense form 02) from tax dollars. If
we look closer at the spending of tax dollars for meals, it is written
that he mainly used this money for his breakfast and lunch and on some
occasions his dinner as well (see
leaked some of the bills submitted for 2010 and 2011).
It is puzzling as to why Dupuis claimed his breakfast from tax dollars.
Most meetings start at 10:00 AM at City hall. Furthermore on some
occasions, Dupuis generously gave tips using tax dollars. Are these meal
expenses provided as a political advantage for meeting with his
supporters? Or is Dupuis generously providing free meals to his friends at
the cost of taxpayers. Taxpayers need to know the answers.
Sudburians
deserve better than what Dupuis is offering. Dupuis needs to
prove to Sudburians that they can have confidence in him throughout his
term in office. He needs to prove that Sudburians can trust him to govern
in the interest of the citizens of Sudbury, not in the interest of
preserving his own political dynasty.
Entitlement
is the result of the overwhelming advantage that incumbents have over
their competition. The playing field also needs to be levelled with
“incidental expenses.” Dupuis
already has built-in advantages like the ability to self-promote with
city-funded marketing materials. As
the municipal election drags on, there is plenty of time to ask Dupuis the
tough questions about the incidental meal expenses. One can be certain
that on the ‘hustings’, councilor Dupuis will have a lot of explaining
to do. The information above is an example of a systemic problem at City
hall that allows for entitlements — the ability to qualify for office
interminably. This is clear abuse of tax dollars and must come to end.
Related
Documents
Related Articles
--------------------------End
Editorial
Released on July 02, 2014 at 11:30 PM EDT
The original
article published on the Journal of Law Economics and
Organization.
The excerpts
from
the article
as follows.
Enforcement and Public
Corruption: Evidence from the
American States
Corruption, defined as the misuse of political and administrative
power at the expense of the citizens, remains a problem in both developing
and developed democracies. The misuse of public office for private gain
takes many forms, from receiving direct payments for illegal acts and
political favors to election tampering to enacting legislation or
otherwise inappropriately channelling public money to enrich oneself,
groups of friends, clients, supporters, or voters. Many studies
investigate corruption’s political, cultural, historical, and economic
determinants. There is less empirical research on what actually to do to
combat it. Researches investigate the effect of increasing enforcement effort,
specifically prosecutorial resources, on corruption prosecutions and
convictions.
Theories
of “system capacity” or “system overload” originating largely in
criminology argue that white-collar crimes, including corruption, are
insufficiently prosecuted. Whether strain reflects lack of funds for
enforcement or career incentives facing prosecutors, system capacity
theory suggests how increasing prosecutorial capacity and resources can
increase the number of prosecutions and convictions
The publicly employed agent’s decision to take money from corrupt
as opposed to legal activities depends at the margin on comparing the
consequences of honest behavior with the size of the rents from illegal
activities, allowing for the probability of being investigated, detected,
charged, convicted, jailed, and expelled from public service. These models
of “economic” factors suggest that more enforcement could produce
fewer corruption convictions, at least in the long-run perhaps following
a short-run increase, as long as a higher probability of enforcement
discourages enough public officials from choosing corrupt activities.
Naturally, since deterrence effects can exist even in the face of system
strain, the net effect of more resources—which effect dominates in
practice—depends on factors were discussed below.
A characteristic of corruption, like “victimless” crimes
generally, is that it is often unobserved, though not in principle
unobservable. Corruption typically takes place as an exchange between
individuals who both, or all, would prefer to keep the transaction hidden.
The clandestine nature of corruption has meant that most research, in
particular that of a cross-national nature, has employed corruption
perceptions of experts as key measures. However, some
researchers show
how relying on perceptions may yield biased estimates of correlates and
causes of corruption.
Occasionally, however, details about corruption do
surface often as a result of actions by corruption enforcement agencies.
As an alternative to corruption perceptions, we employ “observable”
data on the number of convictions for corruption in the US judicial
system. The number of convictions, normalized by population or the number
of public sector employees, is not a neutral measure of the latent
corruption, but reflects the zeal, competence, and integrity of police and
judiciary, as well as the political priority placed on fighting
corruption. At the same time, however, the decision to engage in
corruption is affected by all those factors.
Public employees and elected officials engaging in
corruption run the risk of being caught. In some countries and time
periods, corruption is and has been socially acceptable and a way of life
generally proceeding without interference from the law. However, in most
developed countries including the United States in the period researchers
study, corruption has been recognized as a serious problem and has been a
subject of police investigations and prosecution. We consider how
enforcement resources affect the costs of engaging in corruption,
considering both deterrence and system strain, to specify hypotheses for
empirical evaluation. We also examine what determines the allocation of
enforcement resources, with the aim of correcting for problems of
endogeneity in this allocation, which could, if not addressed, lead to
biased estimates of the effects of enforcement on corruption prosecutions.
We also briefly discuss two additional hypotheses coming out of our main
framework.
Thus, increasing resources spent on enforcement
can have countervailing effects. In the short run, increasing enforcement
resources can increase the number of prosecutions, in particular, under
system strain where prosecution of cases is abstained from for budgetary
reasons. However, increased resources can decrease corruption
prosecutions, if perpetrator adjustment to higher enforcement is
instantaneous (or such increases were pre-announced), if prosecutors have
political ambitions, or if priorities change, either because reducing the
marginal cost of investigating crimes trades off against prosecutions, the
characteristics of referrals change, or if, in a reward system focused on
conviction rates, prosecutors can find it optimal to forego prosecutions
of complex cases with more uncertain outcomes and instead prosecute only
cases (perhaps other than corruption cases) that can with reasonable
certainty result in a prosecutorial victory.
A
valuable next step is to push further the analysis of partisan forces. We
lack detailed data before 1986, but our specification suggests that
changes of partisanship across Presidential administrations alter
prosecutorial effort. If, as in the previous section, we look again at
cases referred and cases chosen for prosecution or declined we can see, in
the case of the Clinton administration, that US Attorneys in 1993–94
filed slightly more corruption cases relative to 1991–92, but not nearly
as many more as were referred. This revealed “effort” clearly declined
relatively more in more liberal areas. In simple regressions (when the
ratio of filings to referrals in 1993–94 is regressed on the 1991–92
ratio and ideology; results not shown), the interaction of ideology and
lagged effort is negative and more than twice its SE. Of course, we also
cannot reject the counterhypothesis that workload expanded faster than
capacity to file charges, leading to the apparent decline in effort,
consistent with the “system strain” results reported above. In the
case of the recent Bush administration, prosecutorial effort appears
politicized in the same way, though with a greater delay, probably as a
result of post-9/11 activities. Also, any apparent ideological bias in the
effort fades out in 2005–06, which maybe why some US Attorneys were
subsequently fired! Further research using this data and other sources,
though not easy, could determine the partisan affiliation of convicted
officials in many cases, and biographical research could in principle even
determine the partisanship of the President appointing the judge in each
case.
Finally,
how general are our results? Several things distinguish our sample from a
broad cross-section of countries: higher incomes, the serious nature of
the offenses (unlike the ubiquitous petty corruption reported elsewhere),
and omnipresent enforcement, without which our model does not work. In the
literature, there is more or less a consensus that democracy reduces
corruption, especially when democracy is synonymous with other related
variables, like freedom of the press and the rule of law. We see no
obvious reason that, conditional on the presence of democracy or the rule
of law which proxy for enforcement, other effects like those of government
wages and inequality on corruption should not appear in a cross-national
analysis. Finding out whether that is right is a challenge that remains
before us.
Editor
WikiLeaks Sudbury
July 02, 2014
Reference
Alt,
J.E., Lassen, D.D. (2014). Enforcement and Public Corruption:
Evidence from the
American States. The
Journal of Law Economics and Organization,
30 (2): 306-338.
Related Documents
Enforcement
and Public Corruption: Evidence from the
American States.
|
|
|